Wednesday, June 5, 2019

The Survival Of Handloom Industy

The Survival Of Handloom IndustyA device which is personad to weave framework is cal guide loom. A part from being primary(prenominal) source of livelihood, handlooms has remained saviors of the dissimilar traditional inherited skills of weavers all over generations. The level of artistic cogency and sophistication achieved in handloom fabrics are unparallel and wholly unrivalled of its kind. The handloom target meet up all needs from exquisite fabrics to everyday use.Spinning and weaving were the national industries of India down to the commencement of the nineteenth century. The spinning-wheel and the handloom were universally in use and it is scarcely an exaggeration to state the nearly half the adult female population of India eked out the incomes of their husbands and their fathers by the profits of their own jade. It was an industry peculiarly conform to to Indian village life. Each woman brought her cotton from village market, and s one-time(a) her recital to the village weaver who supplied merchants and sellrs with cotton. Vast quantities of gentleman sizables, thus industryd, were exportinged by the Arabs, the Dutch, and the Portuguese and the European nations competed with each former(a) for this lucrative trade with India.This paper talks rough the survival of handloom industry in India, during 19th and early 20th century, by examining the multilayered structural shifts in Indias handloom industry initiated by Raj. Historians of Indian industrialization measured that the rich artisan tradition in the region had suffered a catastrophic put out in the nineteenth century, after trade European manufacturer began to flood Indian market. Taken as a whole in the time stage covered in the paper, handicraft producing small firms and industries showed much turmoil and increasing isolation. While many industries lost the market, some of them managed to settle in by reconditioning old silks to apply new goods.The commencement section talks about slowdown in handloom industries collectible to policy followed by British government in Britain for furtherance of her domestic industries and in India to meet the requirements of the manufacturers of Lancashire. The second section talks about expect revolution which lowered the expenses of machine textile and dished in market penetration. The 3rd section talks about survival of exquisite fabrics and high value added products. This paper similarly talks about the supply side harms due to the disbanding of Mughal advantage in 18th century. The modernr section talks about the experience of famine and Swadeshi moment which forced the British authorities in India to resuscitating handloom industries.Policy followed by British governmentBritish, who initially entered in India as traders, established East India Company in 1600 AD and tried to acquire monopoly in trade of India. In 1765, East India Company got Diwani (right to collect tax revenue) of Bengal. Having right to collect revenue in Bengal, Company stopped importing of gold and silver. Gold and silver balance for goods imported by Britain.The roused demand for cotton textile was curtailed by harsh protectionist measures during period 1700-1846. 125 years vast commercial and unfair policy followed by British government is one of the grounds for reversal of pattern of trade in cotton textile between Britain and India in the early 19th century. low attempt was initiated in 1700 to ban Indian printed and painted clothes. This continued till 1846 to do all achievable to retain bullion with them. High taxs to quantitative restrictions were levied on Indian textile. Only under such a ruthless commercial policy it was possible for them to reverse the pattern of trade by coping manufacture of the textiles.As textile market is segmented, they had to compel tariffs even after ban imposed in 1700 and 1721. Additional ad valorem indebtedness was also imposed to annul Indian export to Britain. The t ariffs ranged between 27 and 71 per cent in 1813 and were further change magnitude to 37-67% in 1824 and were completely abolished only in 1846. With this prejudice, Britain was not only able to take over the export market of India just now also expanded to in domestic market of India.Tariff rates for import of muslins, calicoes other cotton clothes manufacturers in Britain1Year Tariffs (in %)1813 27-711824 37-751830 30-101846 AbolishedThese procedures supported and atmosphere where innovation of textile machinery could take place. The machine made fabrics out-competed handloom fabrics of India. Meanwhile the Indian legislature passed various acts between 1833 and 1853 to regulate Trade and Navigation and to fix the Tariffs. The duties levied on some principal articles imported into India in 1852 areArticles Imported DutyCotton and silk piece goods, British 5%Cotton and silk piece goods, Foreign 10%Cotton thread, twist and yarns, British 3%Cotton thread, twist and yarns, Foreign 7%(Source The economical History of India Vol. 2, R C Dutt)In 1859 duties on all articles of luxury were raise to 20 per cent duties on other articles, including cotton piece good, were raised to 10 per cent and those on cotton twist and yarns to 5 per cent, on account of the heavy financial extort after the mutiny. The 20 per cent duty on luxuries was reduced to 10 per cent, and the 5 per cent duty on cotton twist and yarns was raised to 10 per cent by Mr. James Wilson the first Finance Minister of India, in 1860 so that the import tariff consisted a uniform rate of 10 per cent. Dutt 1956 This somehow protected the domestic market of handloom industries.The tariff on cotton twist and yarn was reduced to 5 per cent in 1861 which was further reduced to 3.5 per cent in later part of 1861. In 1874, a mandate came from England that old genuine proceeds, derived from a moderate import duty, should be forgone to meet the requirements of the manufacturers of Lancashire. When every civil ized government on earth is endeavoring to help home manufactures, the Indian government had cruelly repressed the handloom industry.Rapid development of the cotton textile industry in Britain bust indigenous industry in India. No state assistance was rendered in response of the devastation of indigenous handloom in India. It is great to note that indigenous traditional handloom industry constituted wide part of industrial sector in India. Jawaharlal Nehru2blamed squarely in colonial economic policy, which almost entirely eschew tariff protection and did secret code to help nurture Indian industry. 19th century nationalist Dadabhai Naoroji, D D Kosambi and R C Dutt have made similar arguments in their work.The saucily independent Latin American, the United States, Australia, Canada and New Zealand raised their tariffs to enormous height on imported manufacturers which made the matter worse Williamson 2005.Transport RevolutionFrom about 1810 to 1860, productivity advance resultin g from the adoption of the factory system drove down the relative price of textiles dry land-wide, a trend that was magnified as a world transport revolution lowered the price of European textile imports even further everywhere in the periphery. By the 1830s India transformed into exporter of crude cotton, opium, indigo, etc like raw materials. There was a gigantic fall in her share in world manufacture merchandise. The share in 1750 was 24.5% which declined to 6.9% in 1830. American civil state of war (1861-1865) led cotton prices to rouse high. It also led Indian farmers to turn towards cultivation of raw cotton.New high tariffs in old open export bazaar, European factory based productive intensification and unable to shield own markets with tariffs, the Indian handloom industry became less profitable. As if this were not enough, another supplyful world(a) event-transport revolution- induced negative price shock Shah Mohammad and Williamson 2004Railway rates created incentive s not only for the geographical reorganization of Indias economic activity scarcely also for the types of production on which it could specialize. That industry was put at a comparative disadvantage was soon recognized. Nationalists complained bitterly about the impact of the structure of rates on baby industries, particularly those not located at the ports. It was not only the structure of rates but their high level that hindered the development of Indian industry. High transport charges increased costs and made argument with foreign industry more difficult.Survival of handloom producing high value added productsThe power driven looms was on an mediocre foursome to six times faster than the hand-driven loom. Why, in the presence of such a wide productivity gap, did the handloom survive at all?Technological improvements and organizational changes led cost to decline. Unless traditional industry tailored its manufacturing process to the new know-how at least partially to internal ize these cost returns, it could not pro pine as a viable system. Such adjustment itself wasnt an adequate form to guarantee the survival of cottage industry against competition from mass manufactured goods. The former could carry on only when the circumstances existed in the home market which put a premium on feature other than lower prices, as was strikingly manifest in the case high quality, luxurious cotton fabrics and silk. For high value added products, labour incentive techniques sustained to be competitive, while they could not position up against mass consumption produce with economies of large scale production.In the case of textiles which were closely recognized with the socio-cultural ethos of particular regions of populace, pattern of continued existence was visible. But it is important to note that none of these products catered to a high income market.Roy says, Craft traditions in India were extremely diverse. They contained intermediate good (for example, cotton yar n and dyes), tools for the peasants (ploughshare or hand implements), consumer goods for the wretched (coarse cloth, pottery for daily use, molecule milling) and commodities for well-off consumer or the export market (decorated cloth, silk, brassware, carpets, leather goods). The industrial revolution more or less decimated the first three classes. These goods were like in quality and could be produced in masses with machines.3Interestingly, the surviving artisans gained from globalization by obtaining access to imported raw materials, distant markets, and useful knowledge. These adaptations, however, didnt happen everywhere, but remained concentrated in certain towns and cities.Supply Side ForcesWe have already looked in to enhanced British productivity, first in cottage goods and then in factory production, led to declining world textile prices, making handloom production in India increasing unviable. Declining sea freight rates and expansion of railway in India also toughened these forces and served to foster trade and specialization for twain Britain and India. As a result, Britain first won Indias export market and in due course took over of its home market as well Roy 2002. Terms of trade improved significantly in Indias commodity export sector compared to textile, which led the former spew workers away from textile. But we have not yet alloted the local supply side forces like rising incidence of drought and political fragmentation.The disbanding of Mughal supremacy in 18th century led to aggregate supply-side harms for Indian handloom manufactures, even though producers in some area benefited from the fresh order. Profound secular corrosion in climate conditions in the century or so following the early 1700s led greatly to slump in agricultural productivity.Jeffrey G. Williamson believes handloom manufacturing could have been affected with several channels following the dissolution of Mughal hegemony. The first is a decline in overall agricultur al yield through an increased deal burden, faulting of settlements due to insecurity, and warfare. change magnitude of the prices of grain (key non-tradable) and therefore in relative prices of non-tradable to tradable (textiles) was reflection of reduced agricultural yield. Grain being dominant consumption good for workers and grain wages being close to subsistence must have put an upward pressure on the nominal wages in handloom which was being exported Chaudhary 1978, pp 299-300. Downward pressure on profit from both above and below was put by declining textile prices and rising nominal wages.As a result of increased rent burden productivity must have suffered and there is no reason to believe revenue lumber to turn down when British became rules of the successors state. Engagement in territorial disputes by rules of the successor states may also have increased the rent burden reflected by military expenses.Disturbance in Indias major trade routes and increased insurance and transportation cost was because of political fragmentation and warfare. The scarcity of bullock, medium of long distance transpiration, power resulting from warfare must have increased transpiration costs. Fragmentary evidence that insurance rates must have gone up during 18th century has also been argued by Irfan Habib (2003).So, we can say that long before Britain flooded the overseas textile bazaar with factory made products, the rise in nominal wages would have slowly eroded the long standing sources of Indian scrap in those markets. After 1800, Indian textile exports could not withstand the competition of English factory-produced cotton in the world market Moosvi 2002The problems faced by handloom industry in survival can be explained in two main eons. The first eon which was direct result of poor climate conditions and indirect result of the fall of Mughal hegemony ran till mid 19th century. The weakening of climate conditions raised nominal wages and thus lowered Indias fig hting with England and other textile producers of world. Further expansion of revenue farming led to increase in the rent burden, warfare increased the prices and regional trade with the sub-continent declined. Indias competitiveness in export market was hut all more by the increase in nominal wages. Also the inter-sector terms of trade moved against Indian handloom production, encouraging a shift to agricultural commodity production like raw cotton, opium, indigo etc.In the second eon, productivity advancement resulting from industrial revolution drove down the relative price of textiles world-wide. Also the transport revolution in world and expansion of railway in India lowered the prices of European textile imports everywhere.Comparative advantage factorAccording to K N Chaudhary comparative advantage, which has been strengthened by productivity advance on the land or by increasing openness in world economy or both, in agricultural export sector was another possibility of deindus trialization of Indian handloom industry. Increased openness and unambiguous terms of trade improvement are the causes of comparative advantages. In the latter stage this causes lack of competence, little incentive to maximize potential output and limitation of market of handloom industry. Thus, India lost its manufacturings output share to Britain.Special Case of Central Province of IndiaThe rise of British Power, competition from British imported cloth which was because of spread of British imperialism and railway combined with supply constraints led to decline of handloom products. But this decline didnt occur simultaneously or affected all weaving castes equally.British export laced the detailed understanding of Indian tastes in matter of fashion, style and color which would enable to enter the bazaar effectively. The mental testing of Indian handloom goods was ordered by Secretary of State for India to see which of them could be supplied by British manufacturers and remedy ab sence. This official, J. Forbes Watson, had samples of all key handloom products that were in the Indian Museum in London collected into 18 large volumes. Apart from knowing fabrics worn in India, it was also crucial to know how the garments was worn, for what purpose, by which sex, why certain provision of ornamentation were adopted.Watson pointed out that Europe would in all probability by no means be able to make such items as handloom brocades and embroideries cheaper than India. He commented, This leads us to remark that there are certain fabrics which will probably always be best and most cheaply manufactured by hand.British manufacturers met the requisite of Indian bazaar from survey and collection of specimens. At the very time Watsons exertion became accessible, the price of cotton was brought down by end of American civil war and railway from Bombay Nagpur was completed (February 1867). These events were followed by flood of British imports.End of nineteenth centuryTwo de cades years later, it is understandable that the handloom industry was veneer rigorous competition. The volume of imports was piercingly up and volume of export of country cloth even more st unloosenently down. What is more important to note that average prices of textile were down in both classes, but they were more so for the native products. As if this were not enough, the indigenous products also started to face some competition from Indian machine made clothes by the end of nineteenth century four power looms were operating in Central Provinces, two of them in Nagpur, one in Hinganghat and one in Jubbulpore. Then with the arrival of twentieth century, imitation silk cloth in large quantities from Japan entered the Indian bazaar. The imitation silk cloth was cheaper than both Manchester and Indian cloth.Since better off classes still bought fine clothes with silk borders, the section of industry that specialized in producing these clothes survived, but with diminishing productio n. Because of cheapness and carriage of English cloth, it supplanted the products of country handloom. The handlooms were again hit hard in famine of 1899.Edgar Thurston4stated that there was a favorable public response to these cheap imitations of Indian material. He also comments that good taste was the least significant amongst the factors in determining demand.The following two tables talks about average consumption of gettable yarn by sector from 1906-07 to 1908-9 and from 1916-17 to 1918-19 and sources of cloth supply from 1906-7 to 1908-9 and from 1916-17 to 1918-19. This gives us concrete evidence on fall of handloom industry.Annual average consumption of available yarn by sector 1906-7 to 1908-9 and 1916-17 to 1918-19 (Million lbs.)51906/7-1908/9 1916/17-1918/19Total available yarn 689 (100%) 685 (100%)Consumed by Cotton Mills 162 (23.5%) 338 (49.4%)Handlooms 282 (40.9%) 194 (28.3%)Export 245 (35.6%) 153 (22.3%)Sources of cloth supply 1906-7 to 1908-9 and 1916-17 to 1918- 19(Annual averages in trillion yards)61906/7-1908/9 1916/17-1918/19(%) (%)Total available cloth 3839 (100) 3418 (100)Produced by Indian mill 667 (17.1) 1301 (38.0)Imports 2154 (55.3) 1397 (40.9)Handlooms 1072 (27.6) 720 (21.1)Per capita availability 12.6 yards 9.8 yardsHome handloom output suffered significantly, between the two periods it felled by one-third. This is classify from second table. Handloom sector neer fully recovered from this blow. Dharma Kumar in The Cambridge Economic History of India says,We dont know how the curtailment of Indian yarns sales affected foreign handlooms, but second table makes it clear that domestic handloom output suffered substantially, falling by one-third between the two periods. This was a blow from which the handicraft sector never fully recovered.Finally, when the English imports fell off. That finer market was partly taken over by Japanese mills using American cotton.Some good news at the endThe incident of famine forced the government t o discard its dogmatic loyalty to laissez-faire doctrines of non-intervention policy in the economy and caused the British establishment in India to breathe new life into cottage industries. At the beginning of the twentieth century two factors caused the British authorities in India to consider resuscitating cottage industries such as handloom weaving. One was the experience of the famines which forced the government to abandon its dogmatic adherence to laissez-faire doctrines of non-intervention in the economy. Encouragement was also provided by the Swadeshi (home-produced) movement launched by Indian nationalist in 1905.Low7wrote, following the blows wreaked by the cycle famines, handloom industry had undergone something of revival. In the first decade of twentieth century, fruit was generally good. Prices for agricultural produce were in general high and because of famine and plague mortality, there was demand for labour, which was in short supply. Increased spending on public works and railways, sudden extension of the mining industry were undertaken to make good. For all these grounds wages rose, trade flourished, and there was a boost in demand for better sort of handloom goods. 3.5 per cent duty on imported and Indian mill manufactured cloth was imposed in February 1896. Because of this duty, some price advantage was received by handloom industry.Bread and ButterThe machine made fabrics were cheaper then hand looms fabrics but still complete washout was not possible. The rationale for this was that a number of the fragment could by no means be produced. Other people have also argued that sustained attachment to the coarse cloth by poor and unskilled labors wage was much below that of the weavers and fulltime weaver did the weaving job as part time jobs. Land in England was possess by great landlord the agriculturists were mere farmers and laborers. Where as in India land belonged principally to small cultivators who have their own hereditary rights i n their holding. The landlord, were he existed, cannot get rid of those cultivators so long as they paid their rents. Similarly, the various industries in Indian villages were carried on by humble artisans in their own villages and huts. The idea large factories, have by capitalist and worked by paid hand, were foreign to the Indian mind.An individual man- in dignity and aptitude, in prudence and sovereignty- is at his best when he labour in his own field or his own loom, rather than when he is paid laborer under big landlord or wage earner in huge factory. And every Indian believes that landlordism cannot replace the small cultivation and that home industries will survive the assault of capitalism (which is true even today in twenty first century).ConclusionR C Dutt articulated nearly 100 years ago that Britain had transformed India from an exporter of manufactured goods to an importer of cloth, using political power to keep down a competitor with whom the British manufactured cou ld not have completed on normal terms.For the craft production in India, the late 19th century can be designated as a period of structural crisis when industrial organization were in direct confrontation, and the survival of handicrafts depended on their ability to compete in terms of cost and price advantages, superiority of the quality or the artistic merits of handicraft products. The crisis point reached only in the last run of the 19th century when the discovery of chemical dyes resulted in significant economies of scale, and mass-produced cloth began to compete with indigenous materials in Indian markets. Later on, when power-looms had entirely supplanted hand-looms in Europe, Indian capitalist began to start cotton mills in their own country.If the pre-industrial (pre-colonial) production system failed to evolve into a modern industrial structure due to colonial policies, it then had the inherent potential to so evolve, and to compete with the technologies and large scale ec onomies of production during transitional stage, before transforming into a modern, capitalist system.

No comments:

Post a Comment

Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.